Steps to a new world
Sunday, 7 December 2014
One the convergence between the Christian equality and the material equality
Kierkegaard in Work of Love (2009 - Harperperenial; p. 82-83) writes that "it [Christianity] allows all distinctions to stand, but it teaches the equality of the eternal. It teaches that everyone shall lift himself above earthly distinctions. Notice carefully how equably it speaks. It does not say that it is the poor who shall lift themselves above earthly distinctions, while the mighty should perhaps come down from their elevation - ah, no, such talk is not equable, and the likeness which is obtained by the mighty climbing down and the poor climbing up is not Christian equality; this is worldly likeness. No, if one stands at the top, even if one is the king, he shall lift himself above the distinction of his high position, and the beggar shall lift himself above the distinction of his poverty. Christianity lets all the distinctions of earthly existence stand, but in the command of love, in loving one's neighbour, this equality of lifting oneself above the distinctions of earthly existence is implicit."
There are many such treasure passages in Works of love. This passage, and a large majority of the book, emphasises love for one's neighbour. In loving one's neighbour you throw away any distinction of class and truly unconditionally care for everyone. One's object of love is not one's choosing (e.g. one's spouse or friends), but it is the obedience to God's command that one shall love one's neighbour. Kierkegaard is clear to point out that our neighbour is everyone.
What does this mean from an economics perspective? While politicians and policy makers might greatly care for people, I wonder whether this care is synonymous to loving one's neighbour. In economics we focus on elevating (at least trying to do so) one group of people (the marginalised, the poor and the needy) and lowering the status of another group (usually the wealthy). This is often the aim of progressive taxation and is definitely at the heart of heavy capitalism vs. communism discussions.
In an ideal world, where people truly loved one's neighbour, all types of economic class distinction would disappear. One can imagine that love would spur the other to do everything in his/her power to ease the suffering of a neighbour. Love, unconditional love, would expect nothing in return and would gladly sacrifice. The wealthy person who lifts himself above his "high" position would not care for that position - he is above that and hence would care little for his wealth.
In this sense there is no convergence between the Christian ideal of equality and the material ideal of equality. The former speaks of everyone lifting themselves above their station in life to equality, while the latter attempts to bring a balance by lowering the status of some and simultaneously raising the status of others. The economic equality needs a definition of distinction while the Christian equality makes no distinction. Furthermore, the economic equality requires a benevolent dictator (or a decent government) to do the job, while the Christian equality requires the individual raise himself. The ideal of economic equality requires constant intervention, while that of Christian equality is once-off. Economic equality requires a select group to achieve equality, while everyone is responsible for the other in Christianity.
The fact that so many people are still starving today, that inequality is growing, that individuals amass more than they need while brothers and sisters have nothing, point to our failure in keeping up with this command. Of course there are a handful of people that have sacrificed everything in keeping this command.
It brings some comfort in the midst of failing policies and selfish individuals that God does not distinguish between income, race and gender. That everyone is invited to participate in something that elevates them above the misery in this world - if they so choose it. It should be the ideal of all people to do away with distinctions. Once we are able to do that then individuals will take responsibility for the lives of others and stop waiting for governments, or those that already work hard in making a difference, to achieve said goals.
Sunday, 26 October 2014
Solace in hierarchies...
I found a passage in the Žižek and Gunjević
book, God in pain, quite interesting.
(I am not putting forth any solutions - it is just a curious passage that I
wanted to share).The passage looks at hierarchal structures in society and
specifically how to eliminate the "pain" associated with falling in
an inferior class structure. I almost paraphrase the entire section (taken from
p.66) - most of this is quoted from Jean-Pierre Dupuy in Petite métaphysique
des tsunamis.
There are four procedures of hierarchy, whose function is to
make the relationship of superiority non-humiliating to subordinates:
1. Hierarchy
itself: Experiencing one's lower status as independent of one's inherent
value.
2.
Demystification:
The relationship between superiority and inferiority is not based on
meritocracy, but are the result of ideological and social struggles. I.e. One's
status depends on social processes and not on merits. This helps us to avoid
painful conclusions that the other's superiority is a result of merit and
achievement.
3.
Contingency:
One's position on a social scale depends on a natural and social lottery. I.e.
lucky are the ones who were born with better dispositions and into rich
families.
4. Complexity:
Superiority or inferiority depends on complex social processes independent of
individuals' intentions or merits. E.g. despite me being smarter and working
harder, my neighbour's success outweighs mine.
The pillars do not threaten hierarchy, but is supposed to
make it palatable. Dupuy -"what
triggers the turmoil of envy is the idea that the other deserves his good luck
and not the opposite idea which is the only one that can be openly
expressed".
Dupuy further states that it is a mistake to think that a
society that thinks it is just and proclaims that it is just will be free of
resentment. And in these societies it is the people who occupy inferior
positions that will burst out in violent resentment.
Žižek quotes Rousseau's example of perverted self-love: One
cares more for the destruction of one's enemies (they serve as an obstacle to
one's happiness) as opposed to one's own happiness.
What does this have
to do with South Africa?
South Africa proclaims that it is a democracy. It claims
that it is just and free. Yet, there seems to be social turmoil every day.
There are clear class distinctions and those that fall in the inferior classes
are supremely unhappy about it. High income inequality, affirmative action
(i.e. exclusive rights for some and isolation for others) and corruption are
just a few examples of how unjust the country really is. The consequence is
violent uprisings undermining every economic and social activity (strikes,
destruction of property, crime are a few examples). South Africans, and many
others in the world, then surely make a great mistake (in context of Dupuy) in
thinking that South Africa is just and proclaiming it is just.
The ideal of demolishing hierarchy stands in opposition to
the idea of making hierarchy palatable. Are we really able to demolish
hierarchy? In effect this would imply some form of communism. History is
definitely not kind to the examples of communism we have seen - numerous people
have lost their lives for this ideal and almost always the ideals were
perverted by the leaders who exploited the general population. Is the
alternative better? Is it better to accept that things are simply unfair and
unequal? That no matter what skills or abilities a person has, that person is
subject to factors outside his control, or in the very least try to make
something from nothing in what we call capitalist societies (there is no
promise that hard work and ability will be rewarded). Unfortunately accepting ones circumstances does nothing to help starving people, and a system that proclaims equality cannot truly promise equality and food portions of the same size for everyone.
These are deep philosophical questions that touch all of us.
While the South African government has done a great deal to
improve the lives of the poor since 1994, it never, or hardly, acknowledges its
shortcomings (the opposition parties and newspapers do a reasonable job at
highlighting inefficiencies). (We also don't know whether future governments
will do any better). Perhaps this is what Dupuy wants - societies should
acknowledge its mistakes and maybe people will find solace in that - it is
sometimes the government and its policies that constrains me and not my merit
or ability and on the other spectrum that this same government that constrains me helps another who might be more in need (not always Pareto optimal, and not always welfare enhancing) It does not make it fair, but it surely helps ease the
psychological pain of being unfairly treated.
Wednesday, 22 October 2014
Is there anything new about South Africa's latest crime stats?
In September 2014 the South African Police Service released its latest crime statistics. In this post we will see whether crime rates have dropped and what provinces remain high crime zones.
I believe that crime breaks communities and
unity if left unopposed. The recent South African crime statistics do not
deliver any good news. Before looking at some of the numbers, we might try and
understand what factors lead to crime. It is also important to distinguish
between the types of crimes committed. South Africa seems to be plagued by
violent crimes.
Here is what the literature says about the determinants of
crime (some might seem intuitive):
·
Poverty causes crime, but also, crime can cause
poverty (Anderson, xxx). For South Africa the impact of poverty is not that
large, but still statistically significant. Anderson (xxx) finds that a R1000
increase in monthly expenditure increases the probability of a robbery by about
7%,
·
Robberies are higher in wealthier areas. For
South Africa this can be up to 25% higher in wealthy areas compared to their not so wealthy neighbours (Demombynes
and Ozler, 2005).
·
Crimes in South Africa could be a lot higher
than reported (Newham, 2002). I don't think it is too much of a stretch to
assume that a large number of crimes go unreported. Police corruption,
misplacement of documents or the fear of a victim might explain some of this
under-reporting.
·
In some cases it is believed that unemployment
causes crime.
·
Cultural deviance or cultural conflict can also
explain crime (Eide, 1999).
·
The probability of being caught and the type of
punishment are also determinants of crime. Criminals weigh the costs and
benefits of committing a crime and then act on those calculations. This assumes
that many criminals behave rationally and that crime is not always sporadic but
often well planned. Other factors that criminals might take account of in
committing a crime include tastes (perhaps the criminals are bloodthirsty,
perhaps they have an affinity for stealing only small items such as jewels),
ability (this includes intellectual and physical) and punishment (the severity
of punishment if caught) (see Eide, 1994).
·
The Law commission in 1997 and 1998 tracked over
15,000 and found that only 6% of serious violent crime tracked followed a
conviction over this period.
·
Age is an important variable. In a country like
South Africa where a large proportion of the youth are unemployed and
uneducated one ought to expect high crime rates.
·
Blackmore (2003) show that a higher income per
capita, drug related use, urbanisation and the unemployment rate are all
important factors that determine crime in South Africa. I am not necessarily a
fan of using per capita income as this could be correlated simply with
inequality increases.
To make the comparison easy across provinces I indexed the various crimes so that crime per 100000 people in 2005 equals 100. This allows us to compare crime rates in 2014 relative to 2005. Obviously we would want all related crime to be below 100 - i.e. this represents a drop in crime.
As an example the map plot illustrates sexual offences in three periods. In 2005 all the provinces have the same colour (remember that we indexed 2005=100). We can then compare 2009 and 2014 (these are fiscal years, i.e. 2014=2013/14). If a province has a darker colour then it implies that it has less crime compared to the other provinces. It is also important to read the colours from the scale provided. For sexual offences the Western Cape had the lowest crime rate while the Eastern Cape and Limpopo had the highest in 2014
When we look at murder rates we see that Gauteng, Mpumalanga and KZN improved the most.
The Northern Cape improved the most in terms of reducing aggravated robbery in 2014.
Finally I wonder whether overall crime has dropped significantly. The figures show marginal improvements for some provinces, but also a worsening of crime in other provinces. The national figure hardly shows any improvement.
Anderson, M.D. (). The effect of poverty on crime in South
Africa: A GMM and IV approach.
Blackmore, F.L.E. (2003). A panel data analysis of crime in
South Africa. South African Journal of
Economic Management Science, 6(2003): 439-458.
Demombynes, G and Ozler, B. (2005). Crime and local
inequality in South Africa. Journal of
development economics, 76: 265-92.
Eide, E. (1994). Economics of crime. Stavanger, Rogaland
Mediesenter, 158 p.
Eide, E. (1999). Economics of criminal behaviour.
Newham, G. (2002). Tackling police corruption in South
Africa. Centre for the study of violence and reconciliation.
South
African Law Commission, Conviction rates and other outcomes of crimes reported
in eight South African police areas. Research Paper 18, Project 82 (sentencing)
Friday, 3 October 2014
Just how bad is a country's debt for growth
Yes I know that I have a previous entry on the effects of public debt on economic growth. That, however, only focused on South Africa.
Once again public finances bother me. I can't quite wrap my head around why some countries are able to sustain such large amounts of debt and not be in any danger (according to rating agencies) of default while other countries with comparably smaller debt are at risk of defaulting. The common marcro reasons cited for this are long-term growth rates, low interest on bonds, little debt denominated in foreign currency, the maturity of debt and stable and low inflation. Political factors are also important. These include weeding out corruption, have proper expenditure plans in place and don't have domestic strife (investors seem to hate this).
I wish I had time to do a counter-factual and determine how better or worse a country would have been without increasing its sovereign debt. For now we will have to settle with a (hopefully) interesting figure just to get us interested. The scatterplot illustrates the relationship between debt and economic growth for advanced and emerging economies (five year averages from the IMF). A striking feature of the figure is that there is a negative relationship between economic growth and low debt. There is a positive relationship between debt and economic growth for advanced economies between 25%-50% of debt to GDP. Higher values of debt/GDP >50% seems to have a negative effect on economic growth. For EM countries the positive relationship between debt and GDP occur between 35%-100% of debt/GDP. This is indeed a very big range.
What this figure tells us is that aggregating numbers like this tells us very little about the real effects of debt. To really understand the consequences of accumulating debt one has to look at a lot of micro factors (the reasons for accumulating debt, the maturity of debt, etc.). This would be difficult to accomplish since many countries hardly report these variables necessary to do any useful analysis. There is also no reason to believe that debt thresholds are static. The evolution of fiscal policy and the macroeconomic landscape change frequently. We should expect that these thresholds would also change.
Once again public finances bother me. I can't quite wrap my head around why some countries are able to sustain such large amounts of debt and not be in any danger (according to rating agencies) of default while other countries with comparably smaller debt are at risk of defaulting. The common marcro reasons cited for this are long-term growth rates, low interest on bonds, little debt denominated in foreign currency, the maturity of debt and stable and low inflation. Political factors are also important. These include weeding out corruption, have proper expenditure plans in place and don't have domestic strife (investors seem to hate this).
I wish I had time to do a counter-factual and determine how better or worse a country would have been without increasing its sovereign debt. For now we will have to settle with a (hopefully) interesting figure just to get us interested. The scatterplot illustrates the relationship between debt and economic growth for advanced and emerging economies (five year averages from the IMF). A striking feature of the figure is that there is a negative relationship between economic growth and low debt. There is a positive relationship between debt and economic growth for advanced economies between 25%-50% of debt to GDP. Higher values of debt/GDP >50% seems to have a negative effect on economic growth. For EM countries the positive relationship between debt and GDP occur between 35%-100% of debt/GDP. This is indeed a very big range.
What this figure tells us is that aggregating numbers like this tells us very little about the real effects of debt. To really understand the consequences of accumulating debt one has to look at a lot of micro factors (the reasons for accumulating debt, the maturity of debt, etc.). This would be difficult to accomplish since many countries hardly report these variables necessary to do any useful analysis. There is also no reason to believe that debt thresholds are static. The evolution of fiscal policy and the macroeconomic landscape change frequently. We should expect that these thresholds would also change.
Monday, 29 September 2014
Should South Africa tax the rich more?
It is an interesting question. One that is no doubt supported by many people. In my view there is some scope in raising taxes for top income earners, but I think the same also holds for middle to lower income earners. If the objective is raise taxes to finance the deficit gap then raising the top income tax rate might not do much. Let us look at some of the data to understand why.
For the analysis I use SARS revenue collection data obtained from the National Treasury website. They break taxable income and assessed taxes by 24 income categories. The data is slightly dated - the most updated is in 2012. Some basic summary statistics of the data show that:
For the analysis I use SARS revenue collection data obtained from the National Treasury website. They break taxable income and assessed taxes by 24 income categories. The data is slightly dated - the most updated is in 2012. Some basic summary statistics of the data show that:
- Tax as a percent of taxable income is about 20.2% - implying that this is the average tax rate
- There were 14 million (m) taxpayers
- Only 5.8m were liable to pay income tax
- There are about 52m South Africans (See StatsSA 2011 census)
- Of the 52m, roughly 34m are of working age (although it is from ages 15-65)
- This means that about 17% of the working age population contribute to income tax
Given the high unemployment rate it is no surprise that only a small percentage of people contribute to income tax. We can calculate the effective tax rate of the income groups (this is plotted below). It
is clear that there are two tax slopes: R60,000 - R150,000 and one from
R150,001-R5 million and above. This does
not correspond to the hump-shaped statutory tax rate schedule. This is
interesting for two reasons: i.) that some people earn additional income other
than salaries and wages such as dividends and interest that cements these
linear slopes, or ii.) it could mean that there is the possibility to introduce
additional tax thresholds (this often over-complicates the tax system).
We want to compare these rates to the proportion of total
revenue collected by income group and analyse how this stacks up to the
proportion of tax payers. We see that the majority of income is collected from
people who earn R150,000 and above. This corresponds to the number of tax
payers in that income category (the number of tax payers above R1.2 million
decreases significantly). About 86% of total revenue collected comes from the
wealthy 30% of people - meaning that 70% of people only contribute about 14% of
income tax revenue collected.
Just
to see how unequal the tax distribution is we calculate the Gini coefficient. A
measure of 1 means absolute inequality and a measure of 0 implies absolute
equality. We compare taxable income with tax assessed (see Figure below). There
is a more unequal distribution of collecting taxes compared to taxable income
with a Gini of 0.652 vs. 0.558. A heavier weight from on the 50th to 70th
percentile vs. what they actually earn. This does not imply that these people
pay more than what they should (how much each should pay is a philosophical and
economic question left for a later blog entry). It means that there is a decent
sized middle-class that pays taxes.
But just how much additional tax can the government collect from simply raising tax rates? It is very difficult to get a decent estimate. If there are no adverse behavioural responses to an increase in tax rates then the calculation is simply mechanical, i.e. take the lump sum amount add the amount of revenue above the threshold times the rate. Unfortunately there are many behavioural effects of taxes. People may not work as hard as they used to (despite the same working hours), lower income households might stop working altogether if they are able to receive better benefits from being unemployed.
In the next post we will look at some of these effects and try to arrive at preliminary conclusions.
For now it suffices to know that the tax burden is disproportionately higher than on a small number of individuals. We know that tax inequality is slightly higher than income inequality (the middle class pay a slightly higher share of taxes compared to their incomes relative to the rest of the income distribution from the SARS sample data).
Saturday, 20 September 2014
What is that - we are giving more money to Eskom?
The South African government's policy on Eskom is interesting. Definitely not in a good way.
Eskom has received about R60bn in loans from government not too long ago. Now government is giving Eskom another rescue package. And, what has Eskom achieved? It seems like very little but empty promises. The delivery of power stations have been delayed. New project costs are well above estimates. Makes me wonder what project finance plans these guys have in place and why no one is being held accountable for crippling the South African economy. It is definitely not fine that more people are out of jobs because of bad economic planning. It is a crime, and it seems like a perfect one since no one is held responsible.
There are two very funny parts about the Eskom saga: People pay taxes to bail out Eskom. They don't get free electricity for this. On top of that, they have to pay Eskom's tariffs. And then on top of that, they have to pay municipal taxes that add a markup on Eskom's tariffs. These markups differ from municipality to municipality. It seemed like the Treasury was swayed by a possible downgrade. The ironic part about a bailout is that it will put more pressure on the government's finances and could lead to a possible sovereign downgrade.
What does all of this mean? While I don't think that South Africa's debt is such a big problem in comparison with many other countries, it seems like rating agencies disagree (they have been wrong in the past...hint: financial crisis and mortgage backed bonds). It means that there will be an increase in government's effort to consolidate its deficit and reduce its debt. If not, brace yourselves for a downgrade. These are the consolidation options government has:
Eskom has received about R60bn in loans from government not too long ago. Now government is giving Eskom another rescue package. And, what has Eskom achieved? It seems like very little but empty promises. The delivery of power stations have been delayed. New project costs are well above estimates. Makes me wonder what project finance plans these guys have in place and why no one is being held accountable for crippling the South African economy. It is definitely not fine that more people are out of jobs because of bad economic planning. It is a crime, and it seems like a perfect one since no one is held responsible.
There are two very funny parts about the Eskom saga: People pay taxes to bail out Eskom. They don't get free electricity for this. On top of that, they have to pay Eskom's tariffs. And then on top of that, they have to pay municipal taxes that add a markup on Eskom's tariffs. These markups differ from municipality to municipality. It seemed like the Treasury was swayed by a possible downgrade. The ironic part about a bailout is that it will put more pressure on the government's finances and could lead to a possible sovereign downgrade.
What does all of this mean? While I don't think that South Africa's debt is such a big problem in comparison with many other countries, it seems like rating agencies disagree (they have been wrong in the past...hint: financial crisis and mortgage backed bonds). It means that there will be an increase in government's effort to consolidate its deficit and reduce its debt. If not, brace yourselves for a downgrade. These are the consolidation options government has:
- Decreasing government spending. What will they decrease? It will be stupid to cut back on infrastructure spending since this is the only component of SA's government spending that is productive (i.e. there is some future benefit that can be discounted). They will struggle to decrease the wage bill - employment is largely supported by government. They will struggle to cut real wages since they will face formidable opposition from unions. Health? No. Education? No. So it seems like government will not really cut back on spending.
- Raising taxes. I do not think it is the right environment to raise corporate income tax. The economy is still too weak, and businesses will not stomach this (and yet we have corporate profits doing just fine...?). There are also some papers that argue that an increase in corporate income tax only temporarily decreases growth. But we can't really afford a reduction in GDP at the moment. Perhaps there is room to raise taxes for the upper income households. Of course they won't like this since they already contribute the majority of SA's PIT collection. And the additional revenue collection from raising the upper threshold tax rate will be too little. Perhaps government will finance the Eskom bill and the wonderful wage bill by increasing VAT? To be honest, I think this is the most real response to their problem. It is, however, political suicide. But that should not dissuade the ANC too much now - they have recently won the general election.
- A miraculous increase in economic activity that does not rely on electricity. Electricity constraints has played it share in a slumpy growth environment. So where will this miraculous growth come from?
- Inflation. Nope...SA will not be able to inflate away its debt problems. The inflation increases will definitely be outweighed by interest rate increases. South Africa is an inflation targeting country after all.
Unfortunately, it seems that the government is left with no choice but to bail out Eskom. But this time at least fire people who are not doing their jobs. Make sure Eskom employees do not get crazy salaries. And dammit, make sure that pay raises are linked to productivity growth and not some stinking measure! Make sure there are proper loan conditions. And open the debate for competition. The days are gone when South African electricity is cheap. A single supplier of electricity has market power - and market power in the hands of evil men mean high prices. And yes they can charge super high prices since most of us need electricity (the price elasticity of demand is very inelastic).
Tuesday, 2 September 2014
South Africa's unemployment curse
We know that SA unemployment remains stubbornly high. Despite various policy changes over the last twenty years not enough has changed. In this post I point the blame-finger at the lack of good education.
The current unemployment problem in South Africa reminds me of England during the 1800's: Sylvia Nasar paints a rather vivid image of England in her book Grand Pursuit - a rich nation stricken with poverty. Unemployment was high, people were uneducated, communities were poorly developed and it seemed like the rich were simply getting richer at the expense of cheap labour. This last point does not necessary hold for South Africa. While the British are going through some economic turmoil currently, the average life of a single human being is much better than a South African. Somehow the English have escaped the 1800's problems, and somehow current-day South Africa is facing a situation that could resemble an 1800's England
As I see it there are mainly three problems that broadly explain unemployment in South Africa (there area lot of good academic papers on this subject - I don't intend to contradict or necessarily improve on that work):
I will discuss my views on each point separately (they are definitely related too)
(1) Labour is unskilled
Labour is unskilled because the quality of education is shocking. South Africa, as an example, scores very low in mathematics and science relative to other countries (just look at the Pirls and Timss results). Why? We don't have enough teachers, we do not have skilled teachers, we do not provide proper study materials for students, infrastructure is nonexistent in many rural areas (although I think that this is the least of the problems, still severe though), only the rich can afford good private schools etc...
Why don't we have enough teachers when South Africa's current greatest economic problem requires us to have many more skilled teachers? This is a simple economics problem. If there is such a high demand for teachers, then why don't wages increase in proportion to the demand (assuming there is a shortage of the supply of teachers)? Or is real growth in teacher wage bill capped by the quality of teaching they offer?
One would think that SA's high education expenditure would solve these issues, yet there is little change in educational outcomes. One of the things I am curious about is how much of the education spending actually goes into teaching versus the administrative aspect. I.e. by how much do wages change for government employees administrating education vs. wages for actual teachers? I am also curious about a comparison of the employment uptake for teachers vs. administrators in government.
Expect a bleak South African future if the current problems in education are not solved. A low knowledge base exacerbates the problems of the unskilled unemployed and reduces economic growth. Slower future growth will result in more unemployment and most probably increased political turmoil.
(2) - Wage premium mismatch
I often ask myself why critical skills (engineering, education, medicine, science) wages are on average way below wages of finance and management executives. The word critical for me would imply a shortage of these skills or super high demand for these skills - as a result real wages should rise by a lot. The problem is not about critical skills alone, we do not seem to have the ability to absorb such labour and create industries that utilise such labour effectively? South Africa seems to outsource a lot of critical infrastructure projects to foreign nations while perfect solutions could exist back at home. As a consequence we do not utilise the critical labour as much as we should and hence this could explain in part why real wages in these industries are not comparable to finance.
The wage premium mismatch is also exacerbated by South African unions. Let me first state that I think unions serve a valuable economic function and are necessary. My problem with unions in South Africa is that they take an explicit communist stance without any real cause. Marx prophesied that capitalism will cause a drop in real wages over time and result in longer working hours where the lives of people become more miserable. Real wages across sectors have been rising since the fall of apartheid and working conditions have improved for labour. It is true that income inequality has risen. My view is that income inequality is more important for social stability than anything else. Household income and poverty are a more important variables to look at when comparing how people's lives have improved over time - poverty and household income across all income deciles have increased. I feel rather bemused at the crazy wage demands that unions make given that real wages have risen over time, poverty has decreased and household income has increased. Another concerning factor is that the demands for an increase in real wage growth for unskilled labour seems to outpace wage growth for skilled labour. I am not saying that this is wrong - since unskilled labour work just as hard as skilled labour and often suffer physical consequences for that labour; but it does violate certain economic principles and has the potential to destabilise the economy further - I don't think anyone would dispute that union unrest over the last couple of years have hurt the SA economy.
This brings us to out final problem - and a proposed solution
(3) - The structure of education is brittle and outdated
We know that the current curricula is something to laugh at and does not provide our children with the best opportunities for life. We also know that circumstance plays an unfair role in deciding what type of education a particular child receives - wealthy parents are most likely to send their children to top private schools while poor parents have no choice but to send their children to a rural school where teachers do not even show up for work. Apart from these choices, malnutrition and creating a safe environment are also important factors that help explain the success of education.
If we know that this is a problem, perhaps the greatest challenge that a democratic South Africa is faced with, why isn't the government and private sector doing everything to change this? The effort just seems so feeble and pathetic. The myopic nature of government and the private sector will create social and economic problems for ages to come.
Some solutions:
First, education should be provided for free to give children equal opportunities to go to decent schools. Second, university graduates would do well if they spend 6 months to a year being placed in a school to teach an accepted good quality curricula - some people might be unhappy with this, but it is a low cost effective solution and should not be too difficult to implement. Third, teachers need to get a good education and incentives should be put in place to become teachers or lecturers that train teachers. This could be in the form of higher wages, better subsidies etc.
Once this is in place one can start to revamp the school system in its entirety. All students receive the same curricula up until grade 7. From grade seven children get placed. Children who score above a certain mark (let us call this X1) are placed in classes that do proper training in mathematics, science, history and language - these children will be eligible to go to university and study courses that fill critical skills. The children's incentive is that they get to choose their study path. Children who score below the above threshold, but obtain still reasonable marks (X2), i.e X2<score<X1, are also trained in the sciences and are also allowed to go to varsity - but they are not allowed to study engineering, science or medicine. They still have an incentive to work hard - they get to go to university. Finally, children who score below an accepted threshold (X3) are placed into various training colleges that teaches them skills as artisans, administrators, construction and other services. This way we make sure children obtain skills (something that is presently lacking) and are placed in jobs where there is a demand. It will also encourage children to work harder if the do not want to work in these industries.
I really do not see an alternative to the pressing education gap in South Africa. The entire school system is not working and needs to be completely overhauled.
Obviously this is my take on part of the unemployment-skills problem in South Africa. I have no doubt that there are many holes in my arguments. I urge you to help come up with a solution that is better than this, something that is realistic. Or, if you spot serious gaps in my approach, fill them with details that improve it. If we all want to live happily ever after in South Africa then we all need to take this problem very seriously.
In the next couple of blog posts I will try and provide some data on some of the problems I highlighted. I would like to compare real wages across jobs (unfortunately the labour categories in the labour force survey are rather limited). If possible, I would like to compare the wage bill for teachers vs. the wage bill for education administrators in government. I would also like to know how much of of our infrastructure projects are outsourced to foreign national companies vs. domestic companies - can we explain the differences? Finally it would be interesting to get a view on how many critical skills positions are advertised as opposed to not so critical skills - hopefully this will give us a view on the demand for these skills and possibly analyse whether there isn't any mismatching problem.
For some bedtime reading on the huge returns of education on economic growth and reducing income inequality read this and this.
The current unemployment problem in South Africa reminds me of England during the 1800's: Sylvia Nasar paints a rather vivid image of England in her book Grand Pursuit - a rich nation stricken with poverty. Unemployment was high, people were uneducated, communities were poorly developed and it seemed like the rich were simply getting richer at the expense of cheap labour. This last point does not necessary hold for South Africa. While the British are going through some economic turmoil currently, the average life of a single human being is much better than a South African. Somehow the English have escaped the 1800's problems, and somehow current-day South Africa is facing a situation that could resemble an 1800's England
As I see it there are mainly three problems that broadly explain unemployment in South Africa (there area lot of good academic papers on this subject - I don't intend to contradict or necessarily improve on that work):
- Labour is unskilled
- There is a wage premium mismatch
- The structure of education is brittle and outdated
I will discuss my views on each point separately (they are definitely related too)
(1) Labour is unskilled
Labour is unskilled because the quality of education is shocking. South Africa, as an example, scores very low in mathematics and science relative to other countries (just look at the Pirls and Timss results). Why? We don't have enough teachers, we do not have skilled teachers, we do not provide proper study materials for students, infrastructure is nonexistent in many rural areas (although I think that this is the least of the problems, still severe though), only the rich can afford good private schools etc...
Why don't we have enough teachers when South Africa's current greatest economic problem requires us to have many more skilled teachers? This is a simple economics problem. If there is such a high demand for teachers, then why don't wages increase in proportion to the demand (assuming there is a shortage of the supply of teachers)? Or is real growth in teacher wage bill capped by the quality of teaching they offer?
One would think that SA's high education expenditure would solve these issues, yet there is little change in educational outcomes. One of the things I am curious about is how much of the education spending actually goes into teaching versus the administrative aspect. I.e. by how much do wages change for government employees administrating education vs. wages for actual teachers? I am also curious about a comparison of the employment uptake for teachers vs. administrators in government.
Expect a bleak South African future if the current problems in education are not solved. A low knowledge base exacerbates the problems of the unskilled unemployed and reduces economic growth. Slower future growth will result in more unemployment and most probably increased political turmoil.
(2) - Wage premium mismatch
I often ask myself why critical skills (engineering, education, medicine, science) wages are on average way below wages of finance and management executives. The word critical for me would imply a shortage of these skills or super high demand for these skills - as a result real wages should rise by a lot. The problem is not about critical skills alone, we do not seem to have the ability to absorb such labour and create industries that utilise such labour effectively? South Africa seems to outsource a lot of critical infrastructure projects to foreign nations while perfect solutions could exist back at home. As a consequence we do not utilise the critical labour as much as we should and hence this could explain in part why real wages in these industries are not comparable to finance.
The wage premium mismatch is also exacerbated by South African unions. Let me first state that I think unions serve a valuable economic function and are necessary. My problem with unions in South Africa is that they take an explicit communist stance without any real cause. Marx prophesied that capitalism will cause a drop in real wages over time and result in longer working hours where the lives of people become more miserable. Real wages across sectors have been rising since the fall of apartheid and working conditions have improved for labour. It is true that income inequality has risen. My view is that income inequality is more important for social stability than anything else. Household income and poverty are a more important variables to look at when comparing how people's lives have improved over time - poverty and household income across all income deciles have increased. I feel rather bemused at the crazy wage demands that unions make given that real wages have risen over time, poverty has decreased and household income has increased. Another concerning factor is that the demands for an increase in real wage growth for unskilled labour seems to outpace wage growth for skilled labour. I am not saying that this is wrong - since unskilled labour work just as hard as skilled labour and often suffer physical consequences for that labour; but it does violate certain economic principles and has the potential to destabilise the economy further - I don't think anyone would dispute that union unrest over the last couple of years have hurt the SA economy.
This brings us to out final problem - and a proposed solution
(3) - The structure of education is brittle and outdated
We know that the current curricula is something to laugh at and does not provide our children with the best opportunities for life. We also know that circumstance plays an unfair role in deciding what type of education a particular child receives - wealthy parents are most likely to send their children to top private schools while poor parents have no choice but to send their children to a rural school where teachers do not even show up for work. Apart from these choices, malnutrition and creating a safe environment are also important factors that help explain the success of education.
If we know that this is a problem, perhaps the greatest challenge that a democratic South Africa is faced with, why isn't the government and private sector doing everything to change this? The effort just seems so feeble and pathetic. The myopic nature of government and the private sector will create social and economic problems for ages to come.
Some solutions:
First, education should be provided for free to give children equal opportunities to go to decent schools. Second, university graduates would do well if they spend 6 months to a year being placed in a school to teach an accepted good quality curricula - some people might be unhappy with this, but it is a low cost effective solution and should not be too difficult to implement. Third, teachers need to get a good education and incentives should be put in place to become teachers or lecturers that train teachers. This could be in the form of higher wages, better subsidies etc.
Once this is in place one can start to revamp the school system in its entirety. All students receive the same curricula up until grade 7. From grade seven children get placed. Children who score above a certain mark (let us call this X1) are placed in classes that do proper training in mathematics, science, history and language - these children will be eligible to go to university and study courses that fill critical skills. The children's incentive is that they get to choose their study path. Children who score below the above threshold, but obtain still reasonable marks (X2), i.e X2<score<X1, are also trained in the sciences and are also allowed to go to varsity - but they are not allowed to study engineering, science or medicine. They still have an incentive to work hard - they get to go to university. Finally, children who score below an accepted threshold (X3) are placed into various training colleges that teaches them skills as artisans, administrators, construction and other services. This way we make sure children obtain skills (something that is presently lacking) and are placed in jobs where there is a demand. It will also encourage children to work harder if the do not want to work in these industries.
I really do not see an alternative to the pressing education gap in South Africa. The entire school system is not working and needs to be completely overhauled.
Obviously this is my take on part of the unemployment-skills problem in South Africa. I have no doubt that there are many holes in my arguments. I urge you to help come up with a solution that is better than this, something that is realistic. Or, if you spot serious gaps in my approach, fill them with details that improve it. If we all want to live happily ever after in South Africa then we all need to take this problem very seriously.
In the next couple of blog posts I will try and provide some data on some of the problems I highlighted. I would like to compare real wages across jobs (unfortunately the labour categories in the labour force survey are rather limited). If possible, I would like to compare the wage bill for teachers vs. the wage bill for education administrators in government. I would also like to know how much of of our infrastructure projects are outsourced to foreign national companies vs. domestic companies - can we explain the differences? Finally it would be interesting to get a view on how many critical skills positions are advertised as opposed to not so critical skills - hopefully this will give us a view on the demand for these skills and possibly analyse whether there isn't any mismatching problem.
For some bedtime reading on the huge returns of education on economic growth and reducing income inequality read this and this.
Sunday, 10 August 2014
Should the SARB react to a potential asset price bubble?
Yes the title is slightly misleading - are we sure that there is an asset price bubble? Well, house prices and stock prices have increased, despite low economic growth for the last few quarters. Credit extension to households continue to increase. All of this smells like a bubble.
Let us put our differences aside for the moment and continue from the previous posts regarding the conduct of monetary policy. Should the SARB do something about asset price bubbles? If so, should they prick the bubble, mop up the effects after it bursts or do something else?
I am not sure about the right answer. Roubini believes that central banks should burst it. In it he highlights the reasons for and against (check out the reference list).
I think the SARB is facing one of its toughest trials yet. Good luck!
Let us put our differences aside for the moment and continue from the previous posts regarding the conduct of monetary policy. Should the SARB do something about asset price bubbles? If so, should they prick the bubble, mop up the effects after it bursts or do something else?
I am not sure about the right answer. Roubini believes that central banks should burst it. In it he highlights the reasons for and against (check out the reference list).
I think the SARB is facing one of its toughest trials yet. Good luck!
Wednesday, 6 August 2014
How do we explain the disconnect between the JSE ALSI and real economic activity?
Strikes are crippling mines, manufacturing and construction are still not recovering, and inflation is high despite low economic growth and lately interest rates increased. Yet, the stock market tells a different story. It is a tale of persistence and defiance.
I have some hypotheses why there seems to be a disconnect between South Africa's stock market and real economic activity: 1.) People are ignoring all the economic warning signs (see previous posts for some of these warning signs) and continue to buy stocks - they love risk, 2.) the stock market is being led by a handful of big companies ,and 3.) the stock market has not caught up with the real economy. So, I did a little bit of digging to find the most probable hypothesis or joint hypotheses.
Hypothesis 1 will be difficult to prove. I assume that most investors do some research before purchasing a stock. When buying a stock they believe in the value of that stock and hopefully did the proper risk adjustments. This value could mean anything from good company fundamentals, to high return prospects. So let us park hypothesis 1 for now.
There seems to be some support for hypothesis 2. Just doing a quick search shows that the big companies (big by market cap) are contributing to the JSE's historic rise. To be honest the last two days were not that great for the JSE's ALSI. What is amazing about these big companies is that they have massive profit margins! How is that possible in an ailing economy? It could be that these companies have great products (better than their competitors, that is if there are any competitors) and that people are willing to purchase these products at current prices (inelastic price elasticity of demand). Or these producers simply make up the core business of South Africa and people don't really have a choice but to purchase their products if it is within their means to do so. I.e. these companies have market power and operate as monopolies or oligopolies (think of SA's banking and telecommunication industries as examples). A lot of these companies are financial companies. These companies in turn need to invest in some real stuff - stuff that has a purpose and can be used. They either invest in commodities, overseas, in other financial institutions or in the companies that have market power (sometimes they will invest in start-ups if there are huge potential returns from innovation).
There seems to be a feedback loop: You and I observe that stock prices are rising and want some of those returns. We go to financial institutions that are more than happy to invest on our behalf, for a price of course. These guys purchase stock from big companies who hopefully use these investments to do some real investments like building power stations or roads or invent something useful. Real investments increase the probability of higher, or constant company growth. A stock would become slightly overvalued if the demand for a particular company's shares increases price without the company being able to indefinitely invest in new ventures that make the company grow. So, it is possible that the growth in stock prices could easily outpace a company's future growth potential. Remember that stock prices ought to reflect a company's growth potential. The price of a stock would be overvalued if it is inconsistent with future company growth - i.e. a bubble waiting to burst.
So can I make a prediction about what will happen to the stock market in the coming months? You can to some degree with a little more research. You will need to scrutinize the big companies' balance sheets and will have to evaluate and understand their expansion scenarios. I don't have the time for that in-depth analysis now.
Bringing this back to an aggregate picture - the macroeconomy as a whole, I would certainly think that the market is overbought (yes of course you will have to look at selected PE, PEG, EPS and whatever other ratios you can think of). I really cannot think that stock prices can rise without it being linked to something real (remember the dot-com bubble), unless there is some financial innovation that I am unaware of. Thus, I think hypothesis 3 also has relevance. Sooner or later the stock market will catch up to the real economy. This is slightly contrary to the convention that the stock market is often a predictor of real activity.
And who knows whether the economy will improve soon - economic forecasts have been all over the place and none hitting the mark. Using two simple statistical models (a Markov-switching and probit model) seems to suggest that the likelihood of another few rounds of bad economic growth is getting higher (a probability of 1 means that growth will definitely be bad). In my view the stock prices will start to fall. But, this is a prediction that only takes into account a few variables - I might have missed something.
Monday, 21 July 2014
Moving forward
Last night I watched the documentary Zeitgeist: Moving forward. It reminds us of how ill this world is. You
most likely know this. The documentary has a central theme - instead of focussing
on a human value based system the world has adopted a money value based system.
This is easy to observe when viewing business models, economic models and
trying to understand how the monetary system works. It ascribes many of the
world's problems, such as ecological disasters, poverty, inequality and war, to
the failure of the market economy to address true human needs. The documentary highlights
how the market economy ignores many aspects of being human - caring,
cooperation and love. People only have the right to eat in as much as they can
pay for food, or own land or are able overcome hunger by little welfare
benefits from the state. The market economy is pretty harsh on individuals who
are born in poverty. The chances for the poor to attain a good education are
small. Thus the probability of escaping poverty is also small.
The documentary offers some solutions. Referring to the work
of Jacques Fresco, we ought to embrace technological progress, resist the lures
of money and status, build cities that maximise ecological sustainability and
enhances human welfare, and build a system of environmental inventory to
monitor the global use of natural resources. This means that we take only what
we really need and enjoy life while artificial intelligence does the work for
us. In theory this sounds plausible and even wonderful. I just don't know
whether humans have the capacity for such a change.
I agree with the documentary in many areas. I think the
world monetary system is one that enslaves. I think freedom, as promoted by
this system, is an illusion. At the heart of this system lie interest rates. We
charge interest for many reasons. The time value or opportunity cost of money
in one person's hand is compensated by interest paid by another person who
borrowed money. These interest rates are not equal between borrower and lender.
Financial intermediaries (banks) put premiums on loans in order to cover their
operating costs and maximise their business profits. This is why there is such
a massive distinction between deposit, lending and interbank rates.
Furthermore, the way interest rates are charged is perverted. The current model
charges higher interest rates for people deemed riskier (i.e. people with a
high probability of loan default). The problem is that higher interest rates
increase an already high probability of default. The perversion is further exacerbated
by forcing poor people to take out loans in the first place, otherwise they do
not have a roof over their heads or food or a warm bed (some of the most basic
things humans need). The idea that charging interest rates is a bad idea is
nothing new (the Bible and other religious texts prohibit usury).
Fundamental to all of this is pride. The bad world we see
today goes much deeper than flawed monetary systems. It goes to the very heart
of human desire. Our desire is never filled and is an ever growing spiral into
nothingness. We consume, we cheat, we lie, we steal, we murder, we are myopic,
we are unsympathetic and we are self-absorbed; All because we put desire above
everything else. No one is as important as the "I".
There is really
no peace to be found when desire consumes us with flames of empty promises. I
am not as optimistic as the creators of Zeitgeist. To me it seems inevitable
that man self-destructs. Of course I hope that this will never happen. Despite
our feelings about the world we might as well try to make it a better place.
Put aside the gloomy picture of the future and focus on things that are good.
Truly care for those in need and care for the environment in every possible
way. Let go of the desires of being wealthy, powerful and popular; these
desires make the soul very sick and is never satiable. Focus on spiritual
growth. We do not do good and do not feel well because we have neglected a
fundamental part of being human - spirit. We pay too much attention on mental
and physical well-being and think very little of caring for the spirit. I have
followed the suggestion of a friend and started reading the The ascent of mount Carmel by St. John
of the cross. His work has definitely put many things in perspective.
But perhaps easiest of all to remember, and definitely the
most important, is to follow God's commandments. Love God with everything and
love your neighbour as yourself. There is no place for pride when we do this.
Friday, 18 July 2014
The SARB hike might just be justified
The recent interest rate decision by the South African
Reserve Bank (SARB) was not all that surprising. The SARB, with its forward
guidance policy, has signalled a bout of rate hikes when the repo rate
increased by 50 basis points in January 2014. That hike was a bit surprising given low
growth expectations among high rates of unemployment in various sectors. But,
it was also surprising because some might argue that the rate hike happened too
late - if the SARB forecasts inflation above 6% in period t+6 (quarters) then
it ought to increase interest rates in period t. This is if we are to believe
that it takes about six quarters for monetary policy to influence aggregate
consumer prices.
The rate hikes would thus seem justified - the SARB is only
following its guiding law of low and stable prices. Unfortunately this leaves
us with a few unanswered questions: The SARB tells us that SA has a negative
output gap (GDP < production capacity), should we not then expect minimum
pressure on prices from a demand side? We know, however, that South Africa has
been bombarded by a weaker currency and by persistent high oil prices. Thus
there have definitely been some supply-side shocks. No doubt that the SARB will
be worried about second round effects of inflation (perhaps that is why the
interest rate hike took so long).
We need to balance weak demand with strong supply shocks
regarding inflation. A hike in interest rates imply that the SARB believes that
inflation will rise even further. The increase in interest rates will help
(hopefully) anchor inflation expectations. In this case it will delay or even
halt importers to pass the weaker rand onto final goods. This supports demand from
decreasing even further. On the other hand the hike in interest rates will lead
to a decline in demand through lower credit and higher debt payments that
reduces overall consumption. Thus the demand benefit from increasing interest
rates needs to be balanced by the demand loss from raising rates.
At this point you should have been wondering why the SARB
raised rates by 25 basis points. It could be due to a numerical solution from
some model, it could be due to possible fear that increasing interest rates by
too much will hurt the economy, or it could be another reminder of further interest
rate increases.
The problem with 25 basis points is that it does
little to reduce inflation. Using a simple semi-structural model of inflation
(this is just for illustrative purposes) shows that a 100 basis points hike reduces
inflation at most by about 0.4 percentage points (as an example from 6% to 5.6%
inflation). And this is based on an assumption that interest rates have a large
weight in the New-Keynesian IS curve. Figure 1 shows what happens to the model
economy when interest rates increase by 100 basis points. Alpha is the weight on the interest rate in
the IS curve. Output is the level of GDP. The shocks are deviations from
baseline which is assumed to be the steady state. This means that the model
does not take into account nonlinearities such as the response of output in an
already depressed economy. The point about the figure is that 25 basis points
hardly has any impact on inflation. Or perhaps it is exactly the right number that
balances a very sensitive economy from collapsing while keeping inflation in
check. This is pure speculation.
Anyhow, the interest rate is the least of South Africa's problems. Constant strikes (Toyota and Ford have shut down some operations), unproductive people (those that do nothing at one of the many district or local government municipalties), bad employment policies (yes I think the current format of BBBEE is doing harm to the economy) and corruption undermines all the good macro and micro economic policies in place. Economic policy makers can only juggle a sensitive economy for a short period of time before the fundamental problems unravel all that is good.
Thursday, 22 May 2014
A new beginning
It is difficult to move, to leave everything and to start afresh. It is painful to uproot when one becomes so attached to familiar surroundings. The fear of the unknown heightens the senses and obfuscates. Our myopic outlook makes the future a constraint to emotional happiness and quells the desire for adventure. But this is exactly why it is necessary to shake things up, especially if one has been swallowed up into a whole of complacency.
It is has been such a long time since I have been forced to re-evaluate my life. Introspection is part of everyday routine, but doing introspection thoroughly and deeply comes only upon rare occasions. The way I am dealing with leaving South Africa for the US has been interesting and challenging. The comfort of a good job, house, family and friends makes life bearable. Life finds a completely new meaning when one takes all that away. It is not so much as leaving things behind that causes anxiety, but it is the fear of the unknown.
Unfortunately there is no certainty regarding the future, no matter what steps we take to minimize it. Forecast errors grow in proportion to the forecast horizon. Even occurrences occur at random with a given probability and there is just no taking control of it. Moving to a different country adds to the number of already uncountable factors that drive uncertainty.
There are three ways to deal with this uncertainty – you have to or else it will destroy your nervous system:
• Be oblivious about the uncertainty you are facing. This can be justified on grounds that many outcomes are probability events of which you have no control over.
• Fool yourself into thinking that you have control. List the things that causes anxiety and create a plan to address them (your plans might fail which will ultimately force you to accept the first bullet). Thinking you are in control has the psychological advantage of taking away your predicament. While it does nothing to reduce the uncertainty, it does a great deal to reduce anxiety – only because you think you are able to minimize uncertainty.
• Embrace uncertainty and see it as an adventure (I prefer this one). Since uncertainty represent chance events, it makes the future much more interesting and invokes the “anything can happen” principle. Do things that you always wanted to do (make a plan if you don’t have cash lying around to live as a vicarious spendthrift) and maximize every opportunity.
Evaluate your decisions. I am moving because I love my wife and want to share in her great adventure (she has definitely done the same for me once). But, I am also moving because my life has reached a stationary point – complacency is a slow killer.
Change is only stressful because of our attachment to things; Things that have a finite stamp and ideas that do not really matter (such as a job giving a person power and status). In fact, it makes us less human and more like robots that fulfill silly functions every day. We neglect the spirit too often by making foolish decisions and we starve the spirit of nutritious food. No bloody wonder that man is anxious about everything temporal and material – because those are the things we choose to consume and be consumed by.
Thus, while I might forgo a cushy job, a good salary, a comfortable house and leave some friends behind, I gain something that I have been yearning for. I regain a piece of myself that got lost amidst all the heaps of rubbish that I accumulated over the years. And now that I am free, free from the material, I finally breathe again. How wonderful it is to not suffocate under pretence and lies! This is a fresh start. I hope I do not forget this lesson.
It is has been such a long time since I have been forced to re-evaluate my life. Introspection is part of everyday routine, but doing introspection thoroughly and deeply comes only upon rare occasions. The way I am dealing with leaving South Africa for the US has been interesting and challenging. The comfort of a good job, house, family and friends makes life bearable. Life finds a completely new meaning when one takes all that away. It is not so much as leaving things behind that causes anxiety, but it is the fear of the unknown.
Unfortunately there is no certainty regarding the future, no matter what steps we take to minimize it. Forecast errors grow in proportion to the forecast horizon. Even occurrences occur at random with a given probability and there is just no taking control of it. Moving to a different country adds to the number of already uncountable factors that drive uncertainty.
There are three ways to deal with this uncertainty – you have to or else it will destroy your nervous system:
• Be oblivious about the uncertainty you are facing. This can be justified on grounds that many outcomes are probability events of which you have no control over.
• Fool yourself into thinking that you have control. List the things that causes anxiety and create a plan to address them (your plans might fail which will ultimately force you to accept the first bullet). Thinking you are in control has the psychological advantage of taking away your predicament. While it does nothing to reduce the uncertainty, it does a great deal to reduce anxiety – only because you think you are able to minimize uncertainty.
• Embrace uncertainty and see it as an adventure (I prefer this one). Since uncertainty represent chance events, it makes the future much more interesting and invokes the “anything can happen” principle. Do things that you always wanted to do (make a plan if you don’t have cash lying around to live as a vicarious spendthrift) and maximize every opportunity.
Evaluate your decisions. I am moving because I love my wife and want to share in her great adventure (she has definitely done the same for me once). But, I am also moving because my life has reached a stationary point – complacency is a slow killer.
Change is only stressful because of our attachment to things; Things that have a finite stamp and ideas that do not really matter (such as a job giving a person power and status). In fact, it makes us less human and more like robots that fulfill silly functions every day. We neglect the spirit too often by making foolish decisions and we starve the spirit of nutritious food. No bloody wonder that man is anxious about everything temporal and material – because those are the things we choose to consume and be consumed by.
Thus, while I might forgo a cushy job, a good salary, a comfortable house and leave some friends behind, I gain something that I have been yearning for. I regain a piece of myself that got lost amidst all the heaps of rubbish that I accumulated over the years. And now that I am free, free from the material, I finally breathe again. How wonderful it is to not suffocate under pretence and lies! This is a fresh start. I hope I do not forget this lesson.
Thursday, 15 May 2014
The causes of South Africa's next bout of capital outflows
Background
Capital
flows have far-reaching implications for monetary, fiscal and financial policy.
South Africa has a relatively large current account deficit that is financed by
capital inflows. A reversal of capital inflows could have serious economic
consequences. While the economic effects of capital flow reversals have been
studied for South Africa, less is known in terms of what prompts capital flow
reversals. This is the central question addressed in this note. Our analysis
shows that the probability of a capital flow reversal increases in relation to:
- Higher debt service costs.
- Slower economic growth.
- Sovereign ratings downgrades.
- Higher government debt.
The effects and
causes of capital flow reversals
Empirical
work shows that capital flow reversals have a negative impact on the economy (for
a good summary see Smit et al. (2013)). Capital flow reversals cause:
- Sharp currency depreciations.
- Declining economic activity.
- Declining asset prices.
- Current account reversal if unaccompanied by reserve buffers.
Smit
et al. (2013) shows that a capital reversal of 50% reduces economic growth by
0.3 percentage points in the first year and by 1 percentage point the following
year. The 10 year government bond yield increases by 3.2 percentage points in
the first year following the capital flow reversal and by a further 1.7 percentage points the next
year.
Studying
the determinants of capital flow reversals is justified given its effects on
the economy. It is also important in the context of economic movements recently
– South Africa needs to be aware that the potential for capital flow volatility
increases as the Fed tapers down its quantitative easing programme. At the same
time, SA policy makers need to be cognisant of the effects of a possible EU
quantitative easing (QE) programme. By no means does another QE imply an
increase in capital flows – this depends on the factors that influence flows
(the core research question of this note).
The
literature usually cites growth differentials, interest rate differentials, foreign
exchange reserve, prices, financial policies and fiscal sustainability as
factors that influence capital flows. We study the impact of some of these
factors on capital flow reversals. A short description of the possible effects
of these variables on capital flows are summarised in Table 1:
Table 1: The
influence of macroeconomic variables on capital flows
Variable
|
Effect
|
Interest rates
|
Higher interest rates
provide higher yields for foreign investors. These yields could lead to
higher capital inflows. However, these yields need to be adjusted for risk.
If the risk adjusted interest rate is still low, or when a country’s public
finances are perceived to be unsustainable, then changes to the interest rate
could have no effect on capital flows, or even lead to a reversal if rates
lead increases the probability of debt default.
|
GDP growth differentials
|
Higher GDP growth could
lead to an increase in net capital inflows. This often serves, alongside the
stock market, as an indication of potential future gains for investment.
|
Expectations
|
Expectations regarding
the financial stability of a country are important is assessing whether
foreigners will invest or not. We assume that these expectations can be
measured by a country’s risk rating (caution – this is usually only a measure
of risk regarding a country’s foreign denominated debt). It is expected that
there will be an outflow of capital when expectations worsen, i.e. a lower
rating.
|
Inflation
|
Investors are often
interested in real returns to investment. Inflation erodes those returns. In
inflation targeting countries, high inflation would mean higher interest rates.
These higher interest rates in return would reduce economic growth.
|
Exchange rates
|
It is not the level of
the exchange rate that might cause an inflow or outflow, but the view about
whether the exchange rate will depreciate or appreciate. While exchange rates
are endogenous to capital flows, we model exchange rate deviations from
equilibrium to proxy foreign investors’ views on currency movements. As an
example, an investor would want buy goods in domestic currency cheaply and
sell it when the currency depreciates. Here it is assumed that investors
analyse this from an equilibrium perspective – assuming that any movement
away from equilibrium will move back to equilibrium.
|
Methodology
We
are interested in variables that increase the probability of a capital flow
reversal from an empirical perspective. The explanatory variables include South
Africa’s GDP growth differential with G7 GDP growth, debt service costs, the interest
rate differential between South Africa and USA’s federal funds rate, foreign reserves
as a per cent of GDP, Fitch sovereign ratings, sovereign debt as a per cent of
GDP, high interest rates (measured by squaring interest rates) and inflation.
Having so many explanatory variables in a regression framework can easily bias
the results making inference about the size and sign of the explanatory
variables impossible. As such, we use a model[1]
that explicitly takes account a large number of variables without biasing the
statistical significance of the estimates. Our model is estimated over 1997 to
2013q1. Our measure of capital flow reversals is measured as a binary variable
that equals 1 whenever net capital flows as a per cent of GDP is less than zero
and equals zero otherwise.[2]
The model is set up in a way that multiple combinations of equations are
estimated. In total 2^9 (512) models are estimated (there are nine variables). Our
methodology allows us to evaluate the parameter distribution - The distribution
helps us to assess the significance of the coefficients (i.e. how far the mode,
mean and median deviates from zero) as well as whether certain variables are
more important than others (as measured by the Posterior Inclusion Probability
(PIP)). The PIP varies between 0 and 100, where 100 indicate that a variable
was significant in modelling capital flow reversals in all 258 model
combinations.
Results
Table
1 summarises the first set of results. The mean coefficient should be
interpreted with caution. The model is a probit model and the results do not
have an elasticity interpretation. The mean’s sign, however, is important. We
see that higher GDP growth differentials and higher levels of reserves reduce
the probability of capital flow reversals. Higher GDP growth differentials imply
that macroeconomic fundamentals are good relative to the rest of the world and serves
as a signal for potential investors. Higher reserves imply a higher probability
of being able to absorb adverse economic shocks better. Higher debt service
costs, higher sovereign debt and another sovereign ratings downgrade increase
the probability of capital flow reversals. The probability of capital flow
reversals for South Africa decreases in the case of higher interest rate
differentials. Higher interest rate differentials can attract capital due to
higher returns.
Table 1: The determinants of capital
flow reversals
|
PIP
|
Mean
|
SD
|
Growth
differential
|
10.8
|
-0.02
|
0.09
|
Debt
service costs (DSC)
|
34.3
|
0.26
|
0.09
|
Reserves
|
65.5
|
-0.23
|
0.20
|
Interest
rate
|
5.3
|
-0.01
|
0.04
|
Inflation
(infl)
|
9.4
|
0.01
|
0.06
|
Ratings (Fitch)
|
37.5
|
0.41
|
0.62
|
Equilibrium fx
|
15.9
|
0.01
|
0.03
|
Debt
|
18.0
|
0.02
|
0.06
|
Very high interest
|
10.3
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
One
way to interpret the results is to analyse the probability of capital outflows over
different values for our explanatory variables (everything else is evaluated at
their respective means). Figure 1 shows that the probability of a sudden stop varies
over different shares of reserves to GDP, different GDP growth rates and
different sovereign ratings. The probability of a sudden stop is then compared when
debt service costs are moderately high versus when debt service costs as a per
cent of GDP is zero.
Figure 1: Probability of capital
flow reversals
The
vertical axes show the probability of capital flow reversals (outflows). If it
equals 1 then capital flow reversals are a certainty. The horizontal axis measures
the actual levels of reserves, GDP growth and ratings respectively. Reserves as
a per cent of GDP vary from 3 per cent to 10 per cent as an example. The
ratings are assigned numerical values where the highest rating, AAA, is
assigned a 1. As is expected, the probability of a capital flow reversal
decreases alongside the accumulation of reserves, higher credit scores and
higher growth differentials. Interestingly, higher debt service costs are
associated with a higher probability of capital outflows. In the case of having
positive growth differentials, debt service costs matter a lot in terms lower
the event of capital outflows. The probability of capital outflows is larger
when the exchange rate has deviated far from equilibrium. Currency deviations
from equilibrium often imply possible currency speculation – this can greatly
affect the movement in capital flows.
Conclusion
Capital
flow reversals could come about due to a number of reasons. Poor performing
macroeconomic indicators such as slow GDP growth and low-rated sovereign bonds
could result in an outflow of capital. Our results show that a higher level of
reserves serve as a signal to manage potential economic shocks, and hence
reduces the probability of a sudden stop. Higher debt service costs, alongside
higher government debt increases the probability of capital flow reversals
substantially.
There
are some interesting policy considerations that emerge from this analysis. If
the objective is to avoid an altogether outflow of capital then there are a
couple of policy options. Unfortunately policy options that worked for one
country during a particular period might not be that effective for another
country (see Magud et al. (2011) on the effectiveness of different capital
controls). It should be useful to rank and quantify the effects of various
policies that mitigate capital outflows. This reduces the risk of getting
things seriously wrong – such as unattended consequences of a tax on
speculative flows. A convincing proposal has been put forth by Korinek (2010)
to impose a Pigovian tax on inflows to mitigate possible amplification effects,
or externalities, caused by outflows. Korinek (2010) using a welfare theoretic foundation
for risk-adjusted capital regulations, calculates the externalities caused by
various types of flows for Indonesia. He shows that externalities are amplified
during crises periods. The largest externality from flows comes from dollar
debt, followed by inflation linked debt. The least distortionary flows come
from non-financial FDI and portfolio investments. Regrettably little is understood regarding the
macroeconomic effects of different types of flows since most studies use only
aggregate measures. Thus, the correct policy response should control for the
type of flows too controlling for country specific effects.
References
Magud,
N., Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. 2011. Capital controls: Myth and reality –
A portfolio balance approach. National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER
Working Papper 16805.
Korinek,
A. 2010. Regulating capital flows to emerging markets: An externality view. University
of Maryland working paper.
[1] We use a Bayesian Model
Averaging (BMA) that estimates multiple combinations of models and averages out
the coefficients. We use a flat prior indicating our lack of knowledge of the
importance and size of the different variables. This implies that the likelihood
function has a stronger weight than any prior chosen by the researcher.
[2] There are alternative measures
such as any deviation in capital flows of more than one standard deviation.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)