Background
Capital
flows have far-reaching implications for monetary, fiscal and financial policy.
South Africa has a relatively large current account deficit that is financed by
capital inflows. A reversal of capital inflows could have serious economic
consequences. While the economic effects of capital flow reversals have been
studied for South Africa, less is known in terms of what prompts capital flow
reversals. This is the central question addressed in this note. Our analysis
shows that the probability of a capital flow reversal increases in relation to:
- Higher debt service costs.
- Slower economic growth.
- Sovereign ratings downgrades.
- Higher government debt.
The effects and
causes of capital flow reversals
Empirical
work shows that capital flow reversals have a negative impact on the economy (for
a good summary see Smit et al. (2013)). Capital flow reversals cause:
- Sharp currency depreciations.
- Declining economic activity.
- Declining asset prices.
- Current account reversal if unaccompanied by reserve buffers.
Smit
et al. (2013) shows that a capital reversal of 50% reduces economic growth by
0.3 percentage points in the first year and by 1 percentage point the following
year. The 10 year government bond yield increases by 3.2 percentage points in
the first year following the capital flow reversal and by a further 1.7 percentage points the next
year.
Studying
the determinants of capital flow reversals is justified given its effects on
the economy. It is also important in the context of economic movements recently
– South Africa needs to be aware that the potential for capital flow volatility
increases as the Fed tapers down its quantitative easing programme. At the same
time, SA policy makers need to be cognisant of the effects of a possible EU
quantitative easing (QE) programme. By no means does another QE imply an
increase in capital flows – this depends on the factors that influence flows
(the core research question of this note).
The
literature usually cites growth differentials, interest rate differentials, foreign
exchange reserve, prices, financial policies and fiscal sustainability as
factors that influence capital flows. We study the impact of some of these
factors on capital flow reversals. A short description of the possible effects
of these variables on capital flows are summarised in Table 1:
Table 1: The
influence of macroeconomic variables on capital flows
Variable
|
Effect
|
Interest rates
|
Higher interest rates
provide higher yields for foreign investors. These yields could lead to
higher capital inflows. However, these yields need to be adjusted for risk.
If the risk adjusted interest rate is still low, or when a country’s public
finances are perceived to be unsustainable, then changes to the interest rate
could have no effect on capital flows, or even lead to a reversal if rates
lead increases the probability of debt default.
|
GDP growth differentials
|
Higher GDP growth could
lead to an increase in net capital inflows. This often serves, alongside the
stock market, as an indication of potential future gains for investment.
|
Expectations
|
Expectations regarding
the financial stability of a country are important is assessing whether
foreigners will invest or not. We assume that these expectations can be
measured by a country’s risk rating (caution – this is usually only a measure
of risk regarding a country’s foreign denominated debt). It is expected that
there will be an outflow of capital when expectations worsen, i.e. a lower
rating.
|
Inflation
|
Investors are often
interested in real returns to investment. Inflation erodes those returns. In
inflation targeting countries, high inflation would mean higher interest rates.
These higher interest rates in return would reduce economic growth.
|
Exchange rates
|
It is not the level of
the exchange rate that might cause an inflow or outflow, but the view about
whether the exchange rate will depreciate or appreciate. While exchange rates
are endogenous to capital flows, we model exchange rate deviations from
equilibrium to proxy foreign investors’ views on currency movements. As an
example, an investor would want buy goods in domestic currency cheaply and
sell it when the currency depreciates. Here it is assumed that investors
analyse this from an equilibrium perspective – assuming that any movement
away from equilibrium will move back to equilibrium.
|
Methodology
We
are interested in variables that increase the probability of a capital flow
reversal from an empirical perspective. The explanatory variables include South
Africa’s GDP growth differential with G7 GDP growth, debt service costs, the interest
rate differential between South Africa and USA’s federal funds rate, foreign reserves
as a per cent of GDP, Fitch sovereign ratings, sovereign debt as a per cent of
GDP, high interest rates (measured by squaring interest rates) and inflation.
Having so many explanatory variables in a regression framework can easily bias
the results making inference about the size and sign of the explanatory
variables impossible. As such, we use a model[1]
that explicitly takes account a large number of variables without biasing the
statistical significance of the estimates. Our model is estimated over 1997 to
2013q1. Our measure of capital flow reversals is measured as a binary variable
that equals 1 whenever net capital flows as a per cent of GDP is less than zero
and equals zero otherwise.[2]
The model is set up in a way that multiple combinations of equations are
estimated. In total 2^9 (512) models are estimated (there are nine variables). Our
methodology allows us to evaluate the parameter distribution - The distribution
helps us to assess the significance of the coefficients (i.e. how far the mode,
mean and median deviates from zero) as well as whether certain variables are
more important than others (as measured by the Posterior Inclusion Probability
(PIP)). The PIP varies between 0 and 100, where 100 indicate that a variable
was significant in modelling capital flow reversals in all 258 model
combinations.
Results
Table
1 summarises the first set of results. The mean coefficient should be
interpreted with caution. The model is a probit model and the results do not
have an elasticity interpretation. The mean’s sign, however, is important. We
see that higher GDP growth differentials and higher levels of reserves reduce
the probability of capital flow reversals. Higher GDP growth differentials imply
that macroeconomic fundamentals are good relative to the rest of the world and serves
as a signal for potential investors. Higher reserves imply a higher probability
of being able to absorb adverse economic shocks better. Higher debt service
costs, higher sovereign debt and another sovereign ratings downgrade increase
the probability of capital flow reversals. The probability of capital flow
reversals for South Africa decreases in the case of higher interest rate
differentials. Higher interest rate differentials can attract capital due to
higher returns.
Table 1: The determinants of capital
flow reversals
|
PIP
|
Mean
|
SD
|
Growth
differential
|
10.8
|
-0.02
|
0.09
|
Debt
service costs (DSC)
|
34.3
|
0.26
|
0.09
|
Reserves
|
65.5
|
-0.23
|
0.20
|
Interest
rate
|
5.3
|
-0.01
|
0.04
|
Inflation
(infl)
|
9.4
|
0.01
|
0.06
|
Ratings (Fitch)
|
37.5
|
0.41
|
0.62
|
Equilibrium fx
|
15.9
|
0.01
|
0.03
|
Debt
|
18.0
|
0.02
|
0.06
|
Very high interest
|
10.3
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
One
way to interpret the results is to analyse the probability of capital outflows over
different values for our explanatory variables (everything else is evaluated at
their respective means). Figure 1 shows that the probability of a sudden stop varies
over different shares of reserves to GDP, different GDP growth rates and
different sovereign ratings. The probability of a sudden stop is then compared when
debt service costs are moderately high versus when debt service costs as a per
cent of GDP is zero.
Figure 1: Probability of capital
flow reversals
The
vertical axes show the probability of capital flow reversals (outflows). If it
equals 1 then capital flow reversals are a certainty. The horizontal axis measures
the actual levels of reserves, GDP growth and ratings respectively. Reserves as
a per cent of GDP vary from 3 per cent to 10 per cent as an example. The
ratings are assigned numerical values where the highest rating, AAA, is
assigned a 1. As is expected, the probability of a capital flow reversal
decreases alongside the accumulation of reserves, higher credit scores and
higher growth differentials. Interestingly, higher debt service costs are
associated with a higher probability of capital outflows. In the case of having
positive growth differentials, debt service costs matter a lot in terms lower
the event of capital outflows. The probability of capital outflows is larger
when the exchange rate has deviated far from equilibrium. Currency deviations
from equilibrium often imply possible currency speculation – this can greatly
affect the movement in capital flows.
Conclusion
Capital
flow reversals could come about due to a number of reasons. Poor performing
macroeconomic indicators such as slow GDP growth and low-rated sovereign bonds
could result in an outflow of capital. Our results show that a higher level of
reserves serve as a signal to manage potential economic shocks, and hence
reduces the probability of a sudden stop. Higher debt service costs, alongside
higher government debt increases the probability of capital flow reversals
substantially.
There
are some interesting policy considerations that emerge from this analysis. If
the objective is to avoid an altogether outflow of capital then there are a
couple of policy options. Unfortunately policy options that worked for one
country during a particular period might not be that effective for another
country (see Magud et al. (2011) on the effectiveness of different capital
controls). It should be useful to rank and quantify the effects of various
policies that mitigate capital outflows. This reduces the risk of getting
things seriously wrong – such as unattended consequences of a tax on
speculative flows. A convincing proposal has been put forth by Korinek (2010)
to impose a Pigovian tax on inflows to mitigate possible amplification effects,
or externalities, caused by outflows. Korinek (2010) using a welfare theoretic foundation
for risk-adjusted capital regulations, calculates the externalities caused by
various types of flows for Indonesia. He shows that externalities are amplified
during crises periods. The largest externality from flows comes from dollar
debt, followed by inflation linked debt. The least distortionary flows come
from non-financial FDI and portfolio investments. Regrettably little is understood regarding the
macroeconomic effects of different types of flows since most studies use only
aggregate measures. Thus, the correct policy response should control for the
type of flows too controlling for country specific effects.
References
Magud,
N., Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. 2011. Capital controls: Myth and reality –
A portfolio balance approach. National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER
Working Papper 16805.
Korinek,
A. 2010. Regulating capital flows to emerging markets: An externality view. University
of Maryland working paper.
[1] We use a Bayesian Model
Averaging (BMA) that estimates multiple combinations of models and averages out
the coefficients. We use a flat prior indicating our lack of knowledge of the
importance and size of the different variables. This implies that the likelihood
function has a stronger weight than any prior chosen by the researcher.
[2] There are alternative measures
such as any deviation in capital flows of more than one standard deviation.
No comments:
Post a Comment