Steps to a new world

Steps to a new world

Thursday, 22 May 2014

A new beginning

It is difficult to move, to leave everything and to start afresh. It is painful to uproot when one becomes so attached to familiar surroundings. The fear of the unknown heightens the senses and obfuscates. Our myopic outlook makes the future a constraint to emotional happiness and quells the desire for adventure. But this is exactly why it is necessary to shake things up, especially if one has been swallowed up into a whole of complacency.

It is has been such a long time since I have been forced to re-evaluate my life. Introspection is part of everyday routine, but doing introspection thoroughly and deeply comes only upon rare occasions. The way I am dealing with leaving South Africa for the US has been interesting and challenging. The comfort of a good job, house, family and friends makes life bearable. Life finds a completely new meaning when one takes all that away. It is not so much as leaving things behind that causes anxiety, but it is the fear of the unknown. 

Unfortunately there is no certainty regarding the future, no matter what steps we take to minimize it. Forecast errors grow in proportion to the forecast horizon. Even occurrences occur at random with a given probability and there is just no taking control of it. Moving to a different country adds to the number of already uncountable factors that drive uncertainty.

There are three ways to deal with this uncertainty – you have to or else it will destroy your nervous system:
• Be oblivious about the uncertainty you are facing. This can be justified on grounds that many outcomes are probability events of which you have no control over.
• Fool yourself into thinking that you have control. List the things that causes anxiety and create a plan to address them (your plans might fail which will ultimately force you to accept the first bullet). Thinking you are in control has the psychological advantage of taking away your predicament. While it does nothing to reduce the uncertainty, it does a great deal to reduce anxiety – only because you think you are able to minimize uncertainty.
• Embrace uncertainty and see it as an adventure (I prefer this one). Since uncertainty represent chance events, it makes the future much more interesting and invokes the “anything can happen” principle. Do things that you always wanted to do (make a plan if you don’t have cash lying around to live as a vicarious spendthrift) and maximize every opportunity.

Evaluate your decisions. I am moving because I love my wife and want to share in her great adventure (she has definitely done the same for me once). But, I am also moving because my life has reached a stationary point – complacency is a slow killer.

Change is only stressful because of our attachment to things; Things that have a finite stamp and ideas that do not really matter (such as a job giving a person power and status). In fact, it makes us less human and more like robots that fulfill silly functions every day. We neglect the spirit too often by making foolish decisions and we starve the spirit of nutritious food. No bloody wonder that man is anxious about everything temporal and material – because those are the things we choose to consume and be consumed by.

Thus, while I might forgo a cushy job, a good salary, a comfortable house and leave some friends behind, I gain something that I have been yearning for. I regain a piece of myself that got lost amidst all the heaps of rubbish that I accumulated over the years. And now that I am free, free from the material, I finally breathe again. How wonderful it is to not suffocate under pretence and lies! This is a fresh start. I hope I do not forget this lesson.

Thursday, 15 May 2014

The causes of South Africa's next bout of capital outflows

Background
Capital flows have far-reaching implications for monetary, fiscal and financial policy. South Africa has a relatively large current account deficit that is financed by capital inflows. A reversal of capital inflows could have serious economic consequences. While the economic effects of capital flow reversals have been studied for South Africa, less is known in terms of what prompts capital flow reversals. This is the central question addressed in this note. Our analysis shows that the probability of a capital flow reversal increases in relation to:
  •     Higher debt service costs.
  •     Slower economic growth.
  •     Sovereign ratings downgrades.
  •     Higher government debt.

The effects and causes of capital flow reversals
Empirical work shows that capital flow reversals have a negative impact on the economy (for a good summary see Smit et al. (2013)). Capital flow reversals cause:
  •     Sharp currency depreciations.
  •     Declining economic activity.
  •     Declining asset prices.
  •     Current account reversal if unaccompanied by reserve buffers.

Smit et al. (2013) shows that a capital reversal of 50% reduces economic growth by 0.3 percentage points in the first year and by 1 percentage point the following year. The 10 year government bond yield increases by 3.2 percentage points in the first year following the capital flow reversal and  by a further 1.7 percentage points the next year.

Studying the determinants of capital flow reversals is justified given its effects on the economy. It is also important in the context of economic movements recently – South Africa needs to be aware that the potential for capital flow volatility increases as the Fed tapers down its quantitative easing programme. At the same time, SA policy makers need to be cognisant of the effects of a possible EU quantitative easing (QE) programme. By no means does another QE imply an increase in capital flows – this depends on the factors that influence flows (the core research question of this note).

The literature usually cites growth differentials, interest rate differentials, foreign exchange reserve, prices, financial policies and fiscal sustainability as factors that influence capital flows. We study the impact of some of these factors on capital flow reversals. A short description of the possible effects of these variables on capital flows are summarised in Table 1:
Table 1: The influence of macroeconomic variables on capital flows
Variable
Effect
Interest rates
Higher interest rates provide higher yields for foreign investors. These yields could lead to higher capital inflows. However, these yields need to be adjusted for risk. If the risk adjusted interest rate is still low, or when a country’s public finances are perceived to be unsustainable, then changes to the interest rate could have no effect on capital flows, or even lead to a reversal if rates lead increases the probability of debt default.
GDP growth differentials
Higher GDP growth could lead to an increase in net capital inflows. This often serves, alongside the stock market, as an indication of potential future gains for investment.
Expectations
Expectations regarding the financial stability of a country are important is assessing whether foreigners will invest or not. We assume that these expectations can be measured by a country’s risk rating (caution – this is usually only a measure of risk regarding a country’s foreign denominated debt). It is expected that there will be an outflow of capital when expectations worsen, i.e. a lower rating.
Inflation
Investors are often interested in real returns to investment. Inflation erodes those returns. In inflation targeting countries, high inflation would mean higher interest rates. These higher interest rates in return would reduce economic growth.
Exchange rates
It is not the level of the exchange rate that might cause an inflow or outflow, but the view about whether the exchange rate will depreciate or appreciate. While exchange rates are endogenous to capital flows, we model exchange rate deviations from equilibrium to proxy foreign investors’ views on currency movements. As an example, an investor would want buy goods in domestic currency cheaply and sell it when the currency depreciates. Here it is assumed that investors analyse this from an equilibrium perspective – assuming that any movement away from equilibrium will move back to equilibrium.



Methodology
We are interested in variables that increase the probability of a capital flow reversal from an empirical perspective. The explanatory variables include South Africa’s GDP growth differential with G7 GDP growth, debt service costs, the interest rate differential between South Africa and USA’s federal funds rate, foreign reserves as a per cent of GDP, Fitch sovereign ratings, sovereign debt as a per cent of GDP, high interest rates (measured by squaring interest rates) and inflation. Having so many explanatory variables in a regression framework can easily bias the results making inference about the size and sign of the explanatory variables impossible. As such, we use a model[1] that explicitly takes account a large number of variables without biasing the statistical significance of the estimates. Our model is estimated over 1997 to 2013q1. Our measure of capital flow reversals is measured as a binary variable that equals 1 whenever net capital flows as a per cent of GDP is less than zero and equals zero otherwise.[2] The model is set up in a way that multiple combinations of equations are estimated. In total 2^9 (512) models are estimated (there are nine variables). Our methodology allows us to evaluate the parameter distribution - The distribution helps us to assess the significance of the coefficients (i.e. how far the mode, mean and median deviates from zero) as well as whether certain variables are more important than others (as measured by the Posterior Inclusion Probability (PIP)). The PIP varies between 0 and 100, where 100 indicate that a variable was significant in modelling capital flow reversals in all 258 model combinations.

Results
Table 1 summarises the first set of results. The mean coefficient should be interpreted with caution. The model is a probit model and the results do not have an elasticity interpretation. The mean’s sign, however, is important. We see that higher GDP growth differentials and higher levels of reserves reduce the probability of capital flow reversals. Higher GDP growth differentials imply that macroeconomic fundamentals are good relative to the rest of the world and serves as a signal for potential investors. Higher reserves imply a higher probability of being able to absorb adverse economic shocks better. Higher debt service costs, higher sovereign debt and another sovereign ratings downgrade increase the probability of capital flow reversals. The probability of capital flow reversals for South Africa decreases in the case of higher interest rate differentials. Higher interest rate differentials can attract capital due to higher returns.

Table 1: The determinants of capital flow reversals

PIP
Mean
SD
Growth differential
10.8
-0.02
0.09
Debt service costs (DSC)
34.3
0.26
0.09
Reserves
65.5
-0.23
0.20
Interest rate
5.3
-0.01
0.04
Inflation (infl)
9.4
0.01
0.06
Ratings (Fitch)
37.5
0.41
0.62
Equilibrium fx
15.9
0.01
0.03
Debt
18.0
0.02
0.06
Very high interest
10.3
0.00
0.00

One way to interpret the results is to analyse the probability of capital outflows over different values for our explanatory variables (everything else is evaluated at their respective means). Figure 1 shows that the probability of a sudden stop varies over different shares of reserves to GDP, different GDP growth rates and different sovereign ratings. The probability of a sudden stop is then compared when debt service costs are moderately high versus when debt service costs as a per cent of GDP is zero.
Figure 1: Probability of capital flow reversals

The vertical axes show the probability of capital flow reversals (outflows). If it equals 1 then capital flow reversals are a certainty. The horizontal axis measures the actual levels of reserves, GDP growth and ratings respectively. Reserves as a per cent of GDP vary from 3 per cent to 10 per cent as an example. The ratings are assigned numerical values where the highest rating, AAA, is assigned a 1. As is expected, the probability of a capital flow reversal decreases alongside the accumulation of reserves, higher credit scores and higher growth differentials. Interestingly, higher debt service costs are associated with a higher probability of capital outflows. In the case of having positive growth differentials, debt service costs matter a lot in terms lower the event of capital outflows. The probability of capital outflows is larger when the exchange rate has deviated far from equilibrium. Currency deviations from equilibrium often imply possible currency speculation – this can greatly affect the movement in capital flows.

Conclusion
Capital flow reversals could come about due to a number of reasons. Poor performing macroeconomic indicators such as slow GDP growth and low-rated sovereign bonds could result in an outflow of capital. Our results show that a higher level of reserves serve as a signal to manage potential economic shocks, and hence reduces the probability of a sudden stop. Higher debt service costs, alongside higher government debt increases the probability of capital flow reversals substantially.

There are some interesting policy considerations that emerge from this analysis. If the objective is to avoid an altogether outflow of capital then there are a couple of policy options. Unfortunately policy options that worked for one country during a particular period might not be that effective for another country (see Magud et al. (2011) on the effectiveness of different capital controls). It should be useful to rank and quantify the effects of various policies that mitigate capital outflows. This reduces the risk of getting things seriously wrong – such as unattended consequences of a tax on speculative flows. A convincing proposal has been put forth by Korinek (2010) to impose a Pigovian tax on inflows to mitigate possible amplification effects, or externalities, caused by outflows. Korinek (2010) using a welfare theoretic foundation for risk-adjusted capital regulations, calculates the externalities caused by various types of flows for Indonesia. He shows that externalities are amplified during crises periods. The largest externality from flows comes from dollar debt, followed by inflation linked debt. The least distortionary flows come from non-financial FDI and portfolio investments.  Regrettably little is understood regarding the macroeconomic effects of different types of flows since most studies use only aggregate measures. Thus, the correct policy response should control for the type of flows too controlling for country specific effects.

References
Magud, N., Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. 2011. Capital controls: Myth and reality – A portfolio balance approach. National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Papper 16805.

Korinek, A. 2010. Regulating capital flows to emerging markets: An externality view. University of Maryland working paper.  



[1] We use a Bayesian Model Averaging (BMA) that estimates multiple combinations of models and averages out the coefficients. We use a flat prior indicating our lack of knowledge of the importance and size of the different variables. This implies that the likelihood function has a stronger weight than any prior chosen by the researcher. 
[2] There are alternative measures such as any deviation in capital flows of more than one standard deviation.